[Paleopsych] Larry Summers: Remarks at NBER Conference on Diversifying the Science & Engineering Workforce
Premise Checker
checker at panix.com
Wed Apr 13 17:48:12 UTC 2005
Remarks at NBER Conference on Diversifying the Science & Engineering Workforce
http://www.president.harvard.edu/speeches/2005/nber.html
[The 1/14 referred to in the Edge 158 on assortive mating theory I sent a
moment ago was evidently this conference where Summers undertook his
wicked hypothesizing that caused at least one audience member to leave
lest she vomit.]
Remarks at NBER Conference on Diversifying the Science & Engineering
Workforce
Lawrence H. Summers
Cambridge, Mass.
January 14, 2005
I asked Richard, when he invited me to come here and speak, whether he
wanted an institutional talk about Harvard's policies toward diversity
or whether he wanted some questions asked and some attempts at
provocation, because I was willing to do the second and didn't feel
like doing the first. And so we have agreed that I am speaking
unofficially and not using this as an occasion to lay out the many
things we're doing at Harvard to promote the crucial objective of
diversity. There are many aspects of the problems you're discussing
and it seems to me they're all very important from a national point of
view. I'm going to confine myself to addressing one portion of the
problem, or of the challenge we're discussing, which is the issue of
women's representation in tenured positions in science and engineering
at top universities and research institutions, not because that's
necessarily the most important problem or the most interesting
problem, but because it's the only one of these problems that I've
made an effort to think in a very serious way about. The other
prefatory comment that I would make is that I am going to, until most
of the way through, attempt to adopt an entirely positive, rather than
normative approach, and just try to think about and offer some
hypotheses as to why we observe what we observe without seeing this
through the kind of judgmental tendency that inevitably is connected
with all our common goals of equality. It is after all not the case
that the role of women in science is the only example of a group that
is significantly underrepresented in an important activity and whose
underrepresentation contributes to a shortage of role models for
others who are considering being in that group. To take a set of
diverse examples, the data will, I am confident, reveal that Catholics
are substantially underrepresented in investment banking, which is an
enormously high-paying profession in our society; that white men are
very substantially underrepresented in the National Basketball
Association; and that Jews are very substantially underrepresented in
farming and in agriculture. These are all phenomena in which one
observes underrepresentation, and I think it's important to try to
think systematically and clinically about the reasons for
underrepresentation.
There are three broad hypotheses about the sources of the very
substantial disparities that this conference's papers document and
have been documented before with respect to the presence of women in
high-end scientific professions. One is what I would call the-I'll
explain each of these in a few moments and comment on how important I
think they are-the first is what I call the high-powered job
hypothesis. The second is what I would call different availability of
aptitude at the high end, and the third is what I would call different
socialization and patterns of discrimination in a search. And in my
own view, their importance probably ranks in exactly the order that I
just described.
Maybe it would be helpful to just, for a moment, broaden the problem,
or the issue, beyond science and engineering. I've had the opportunity
to discuss questions like this with chief executive officers at major
corporations, the managing partners of large law firms, the directors
of prominent teaching hospitals, and with the leaders of other
prominent professional service organizations, as well as with
colleagues in higher education. In all of those groups, the story is
fundamentally the same. Twenty or twenty-five years ago, we started to
see very substantial increases in the number of women who were in
graduate school in this field. Now the people who went to graduate
school when that started are forty, forty-five, fifty years old. If
you look at the top cohort in our activity, it is not only nothing
like fifty-fifty, it is nothing like what we thought it was when we
started having a third of the women, a third of the law school class
being female, twenty or twenty-five years ago. And the relatively few
women who are in the highest ranking places are disproportionately
either unmarried or without children, with the emphasis differing
depending on just who you talk to. And that is a reality that is
present and that one has exactly the same conversation in almost any
high-powered profession. What does one make of that? I think it is
hard-and again, I am speaking completely descriptively and
non-normatively-to say that there are many professions and many
activities, and the most prestigious activities in our society expect
of people who are going to rise to leadership positions in their
forties near total commitments to their work. They expect a large
number of hours in the office, they expect a flexibility of schedules
to respond to contingency, they expect a continuity of effort through
the life cycle, and they expect-and this is harder to measure-but they
expect that the mind is always working on the problems that are in the
job, even when the job is not taking place. And it is a fact about our
society that that is a level of commitment that a much higher fraction
of married men have been historically prepared to make than of married
women. That's not a judgment about how it should be, not a judgment
about what they should expect. But it seems to me that it is very hard
to look at the data and escape the conclusion that that expectation is
meeting with the choices that people make and is contributing
substantially to the outcomes that we observe. One can put it
differently. Of a class, and the work that Claudia Goldin and Larry
Katz are doing will, I'm sure, over time, contribute greatly to our
understanding of these issues and for all I know may prove my
conjectures completely wrong. Another way to put the point is to say,
what fraction of young women in their mid-twenties make a decision
that they don't want to have a job that they think about eighty hours
a week. What fraction of young men make a decision that they're
unwilling to have a job that they think about eighty hours a week, and
to observe what the difference is. And that has got to be a large part
of what is observed. Now that begs entirely the normative
questions-which I'll get to a little later-of, is our society right to
expect that level of effort from people who hold the most prominent
jobs? Is our society right to have familial arrangements in which
women are asked to make that choice and asked more to make that choice
than men? Is our society right to ask of anybody to have a prominent
job at this level of intensity, and I think those are all questions
that I want to come back to. But it seems to me that it is impossible
to look at this pattern and look at its pervasiveness and not conclude
that something of the sort that I am describing has to be of
significant importance. To buttress conviction and theory with
anecdote, a young woman who worked very closely with me at the
Treasury and who has subsequently gone on to work at Google highly
successfully, is a 1994 graduate of Harvard Business School. She
reports that of her first year section, there were twenty-two women,
of whom three are working full time at this point. That may, the dean
of the Business School reports to me, that that is not an implausible
observation given their experience with their alumnae. So I think in
terms of positive understanding, the first very important reality is
just what I would call the, who wants to do high-powered intense work?
The second thing that I think one has to recognize is present is what
I would call the combination of, and here, I'm focusing on something
that would seek to answer the question of why is the pattern different
in science and engineering, and why is the representation even lower
and more problematic in science and engineering than it is in other
fields. And here, you can get a fair distance, it seems to me, looking
at a relatively simple hypothesis. It does appear that on many, many
different human attributes-height, weight, propensity for criminality,
overall IQ, mathematical ability, scientific ability-there is
relatively clear evidence that whatever the difference in means-which
can be debated-there is a difference in the standard deviation, and
variability of a male and a female population. And that is true with
respect to attributes that are and are not plausibly, culturally
determined. If one supposes, as I think is reasonable, that if one is
talking about physicists at a top twenty-five research university, one
is not talking about people who are two standard deviations above the
mean. And perhaps it's not even talking about somebody who is three
standard deviations above the mean. But it's talking about people who
are three and a half, four standard deviations above the mean in the
one in 5,000, one in 10,000 class. Even small differences in the
standard deviation will translate into very large differences in the
available pool substantially out. I did a very crude calculation,
which I'm sure was wrong and certainly was unsubtle, twenty different
ways. I looked at the Xie and Shauman paper-looked at the book,
rather-looked at the evidence on the sex ratios in the top 5% of
twelfth graders. If you look at those-they're all over the map,
depends on which test, whether it's math, or science, and so forth-but
50% women, one woman for every two men, would be a high-end estimate
from their estimates. From that, you can back out a difference in the
implied standard deviations that works out to be about 20%. And from
that, you can work out the difference out several standard deviations.
If you do that calculation-and I have no reason to think that it
couldn't be refined in a hundred ways-you get five to one, at the high
end. Now, it's pointed out by one of the papers at this conference
that these tests are not a very good measure and are not highly
predictive with respect to people's ability to do that. And that's
absolutely right. But I don't think that resolves the issue at all.
Because if my reading of the data is right-it's something people can
argue about-that there are some systematic differences in variability
in different populations, then whatever the set of attributes are that
are precisely defined to correlate with being an aeronautical engineer
at MIT or being a chemist at Berkeley, those are probably different in
their standard deviations as well. So my sense is that the unfortunate
truth-I would far prefer to believe something else, because it would
be easier to address what is surely a serious social problem if
something else were true-is that the combination of the high-powered
job hypothesis and the differing variances probably explains a fair
amount of this problem.
There may also be elements, by the way, of differing, there is some,
particularly in some attributes, that bear on engineering, there is
reasonably strong evidence of taste differences between little girls
and little boys that are not easy to attribute to socialization. I
just returned from Israel, where we had the opportunity to visit a
kibbutz, and to spend some time talking about the history of the
kibbutz movement, and it is really very striking to hear how the
movement started with an absolute commitment, of a kind one doesn't
encounter in other places, that everybody was going to do the same
jobs. Sometimes the women were going to fix the tractors, and the men
were going to work in the nurseries, sometimes the men were going to
fix the tractors and the women were going to work in the nurseries,
and just under the pressure of what everyone wanted, in a hundred
different kibbutzes, each one of which evolved, it all moved in the
same direction. So, I think, while I would prefer to believe
otherwise, I guess my experience with my two and a half year old twin
daughters who were not given dolls and who were given trucks, and
found themselves saying to each other, look, daddy truck is carrying
the baby truck, tells me something. And I think it's just something
that you probably have to recognize. There are two other hypotheses
that are all over. One is socialization. Somehow little girls are all
socialized towards nursing and little boys are socialized towards
building bridges. No doubt there is some truth in that. I would be
hesitant about assigning too much weight to that hypothesis for two
reasons. First, most of what we've learned from empirical psychology
in the last fifteen years has been that people naturally attribute
things to socialization that are in fact not attributable to
socialization. We've been astounded by the results of separated twins
studies. The confident assertions that autism was a reflection of
parental characteristics that were absolutely supported and that
people knew from years of observational evidence have now been proven
to be wrong. And so, the human mind has a tendency to grab to the
socialization hypothesis when you can see it, and it often turns out
not to be true. The second empirical problem is that girls are
persisting longer and longer. When there were no girls majoring in
chemistry, when there were no girls majoring in biology, it was much
easier to blame parental socialization. Then, as we are increasingly
finding today, the problem is what's happening when people are twenty,
or when people are twenty-five, in terms of their patterns, with which
they drop out. Again, to the extent it can be addressed, it's a
terrific thing to address.
The most controversial in a way, question, and the most difficult
question to judge, is what is the role of discrimination? To what
extent is there overt discrimination? Surely there is some. Much more
tellingly, to what extent are there pervasive patterns of passive
discrimination and stereotyping in which people like to choose people
like themselves, and the people in the previous group are
disproportionately white male, and so they choose people who are like
themselves, who are disproportionately white male. No one who's been
in a university department or who has been involved in personnel
processes can deny that this kind of taste does go on, and it is
something that happens, and it is something that absolutely,
vigorously needs to be combated. On the other hand, I think before
regarding it as pervasive, and as the dominant explanation of the
patterns we observe, there are two points that should make one
hesitate. The first is the fallacy of composition. No doubt it is true
that if any one institution makes a major effort to focus on reducing
stereotyping, on achieving diversity, on hiring more people, no doubt
it can succeed in hiring more. But each person it hires will come from
a different institution, and so everyone observes that when an
institution works very hard at this, to some extent they are able to
produce better results. If I stand up at a football game and everybody
else is sitting down, I can see much better, but if everybody stands
up, the views may get a little better, but they don't get a lot
better. And there's a real question as to how plausible it is to
believe that there is anything like half as many people who are
qualified to be scientists at top ten schools and who are now not at
top ten schools, and that's the argument that one has to make in
thinking about this as a national problem rather than an individual
institutional problem. The second problem is the one that Gary Becker
very powerfully pointed out in addressing racial discrimination many
years ago. If it was really the case that everybody was
discriminating, there would be very substantial opportunities for a
limited number of people who were not prepared to discriminate to
assemble remarkable departments of high quality people at relatively
limited cost simply by the act of their not discriminating, because of
what it would mean for the pool that was available. And there are
certainly examples of institutions that have focused on increasing
their diversity to their substantial benefit, but if there was really
a pervasive pattern of discrimination that was leaving an
extraordinary number of high-quality potential candidates behind, one
suspects that in the highly competitive academic marketplace, there
would be more examples of institutions that succeeded substantially by
working to fill the gap. And I think one sees relatively little
evidence of that. So my best guess, to provoke you, of what's behind
all of this is that the largest phenomenon, by far, is the general
clash between people's legitimate family desires and employers'
current desire for high power and high intensity, that in the special
case of science and engineering, there are issues of intrinsic
aptitude, and particularly of the variability of aptitude, and that
those considerations are reinforced by what are in fact lesser factors
involving socialization and continuing discrimination. I would like
nothing better than to be proved wrong, because I would like nothing
better than for these problems to be addressable simply by everybody
understanding what they are, and working very hard to address them.
What's to be done? And what further questions should one know the
answers to? Let me take a second, first to just remark on a few
questions that it seems to me are ripe for research, and for all I
know, some of them have been researched. First, it would be very
useful to know, with hard data, what the quality of marginal hires are
when major diversity efforts are mounted. When major diversity efforts
are mounted, and consciousness is raised, and special efforts are
made, and you look five years later at the quality of the people who
have been hired during that period, how many are there who have turned
out to be much better than the institutional norm who wouldn't have
been found without a greater search. And how many of them are
plausible compromises that aren't unreasonable, and how many of them
are what the right-wing critics of all of this suppose represent clear
abandonments of quality standards. I don't know the answer, but I
think if people want to move the world on this question, they have to
be willing to ask the question in ways that could face any possible
answer that came out. Second, and by the way, I think a more
systematic effort to look at citation records of male and female
scholars in disciplines where citations are relatively well-correlated
with academic rank and with people's judgments of quality would be
very valuable. Of course, most of the critiques of citations go to
reasons why they should not be useful in judging an individual
scholar. Most of them are not reasons why they would not be useful in
comparing two large groups of scholars and so there is significant
potential, it seems to me, for citation analysis in this regard.
Second, what about objective versus subjective factors in hiring? I've
been exposed, by those who want to see the university hiring practices
changed to favor women more and to assure more diversity, to two very
different views. One group has urged that we make the processes
consistently more clear-cut and objective, based on papers, numbers of
papers published, numbers of articles cited, objectivity, measurement
of performance, no judgments of potential, no reference to other
things, because if it's made more objective, the subjectivity that is
associated with discrimination and which invariably works to the
disadvantage of minority groups will not be present. I've also been
exposed to exactly the opposite view, that those criteria and those
objective criteria systematically bias the comparisons away from many
attributes that those who contribute to the diversity have: a greater
sense of collegiality, a greater sense of institutional
responsibility. Somebody ought to be able to figure out the answer to
the question of, if you did it more objectively versus less
objectively, what would happen. Then you can debate whether you should
or whether you shouldn't, if objective or subjective is better. But
that question ought to be a question that has an answer, that people
can find. Third, the third kind of question is, what do we know about
search procedures in universities? Is it the case that more systematic
comprehensive search processes lead to minority group members who
otherwise would have not been noticed being noticed? Or does
fetishizing the search procedure make it very difficult to pursue the
targets of opportunity that are often available arising out of
particular family situations or particular moments, and does
fetishizing and formalizing search procedures further actually work to
the disadvantage of minority group members. Again, everybody's got an
opinion; I don't think anybody actually has a clue as to what the
answer is. Fourth, what do we actually know about the incidence of
financial incentives and other support for child care in terms of what
happens to people's career patterns. I've been struck at Harvard that
there's something unfortunate and ironic about the fact that if you're
a faculty member and you have a kid who's 18 who goes to college, we
in effect, through an interest-free loan, give you about $9,000. If
you have a six-year-old, we give you nothing. And I don't think we're
very different from most other universities in this regard, but there
is something odd about that strategic choice, if the goal is to
recruit people to come to the university. But I don't think we know
much about the child care issue. The fifth question-which it seems to
me would be useful to study and to actually learn the answer to-is
what do we know, or what can we learn, about the costs of career
interruptions. There is something we would like to believe. We would
like to believe that you can take a year off, or two years off, or
three years off, or be half-time for five years, and it affects your
productivity during the time, but that it really doesn't have any
fundamental effect on the career path. And a whole set of conclusions
would follow from that in terms of flexible work arrangements and so
forth. And the question is, in what areas of academic life and in what
ways is it actually true. Somebody reported to me on a study that they
found, I don't remember who had told me about this-maybe it was you,
Richard-that there was a very clear correlation between the average
length of time, from the time a paper was cited. That is, in fields
where the average papers cited had been written nine months ago, women
had a much harder time than in fields where the average thing cited
had been written ten years ago. And that is suggestive in this regard.
On the discouraging side of it, someone remarked once that no
economist who had gone to work at the President's Council of Economic
Advisors for two years had done highly important academic work after
they returned. Now, I'm sure there are counterexamples to that, and
I'm sure people are kind of processing that Tobin's Q is the
best-known counterexample to that proposition, and there are obviously
different kinds of effects that happen from working in Washington for
two years. But it would be useful to explore a variety of kinds of
natural interruption experiments, to see what actual difference it
makes, and to see whether it's actually true, and to see in what ways
interruptions can be managed, and in what fields it makes a
difference. I think it's an area in which there's conviction but where
it doesn't seem to me there's an enormous amount of evidence. What
should we all do? I think the case is overwhelming for employers
trying to be the [unintelligible] employer who responds to everybody
else's discrimination by competing effectively to locate people who
others are discriminating against, or to provide different
compensation packages that will attract the people who would otherwise
have enormous difficulty with child care. I think a lot of discussion
of issues around child care, issues around extending tenure clocks,
issues around providing family benefits, are enormously important. I
think there's a strong case for monitoring and making sure that
searches are done very carefully and that there are enough people
looking and watching that that pattern of choosing people like
yourself is not allowed to take insidious effect. But I think it's
something that has to be done with very great care because it slides
easily into pressure to achieve given fractions in given years, which
runs the enormous risk of people who were hired because they were
terrific being made to feel, or even if not made to feel, being seen
by others as having been hired for some other reason. And I think
that's something we all need to be enormously careful of as we
approach these issues, and it's something we need to do, but I think
it's something that we need to do with great care.
Let me just conclude by saying that I've given you my best guesses
after a fair amount of reading the literature and a lot of talking to
people. They may be all wrong. I will have served my purpose if I have
provoked thought on this question and provoked the marshalling of
evidence to contradict what I have said. But I think we all need to be
thinking very hard about how to do better on these issues and that
they are too important to sentimentalize rather than to think about in
as rigorous and careful ways as we can. That's why I think conferences
like this are very, very valuable. Thank you.
Questions and Answers
Q: Well, I don't want to take up much time because I know other people
have questions, so, first of all I'd like to say thank you for your
input. It's very interesting-I noticed it's being recorded so I hope
that we'll be able to have a copy of it. That would be nice.
LHS: We'll see. (LAUGHTER)
Q: Secondly, you make a point, which I very much agree with, that this
is a wonderful opportunity for other universities to hire women and
minorities, and you said you didn't have an example of an instance in
which that is being done. The chemistry department at Rutgers is doing
that, and they are bragging about it and they are saying, "Any woman
who is having problems in her home department, send me your resume."
They are now at twenty-five percent women, which is double the
national average-among the top fifty universities-so I agree with you
on that. I think it is a wonderful opportunity and I hope others
follow that example. One thing that I do sort of disagree with is the
use of identical twins that have been separated and their environment
followed. I think that the environments that a lot of women and
minorities experience would not be something that would be-that a twin
would be subjected to if the person knows that their environment is
being watched. Because a lot of the things that are done to women and
minorities are simply illegal, and so they'll never experience that.
LHS: I don't think that. I don't actually think that's the point at
all. My point was a very different one. My point was simply that the
field of behavioral genetics had a revolution in the last fifteen
years, and the principal thrust of that revolution was the discovery
that a large number of things that people thought were due to
socialization weren't, and were in fact due to more intrinsic human
nature, and that set of discoveries, it seemed to me, ought to
influence the way one thought about other areas where there was a
perception of the importance of socialization. I wasn't at all trying
to connect those studies to the particular experiences of women and
minorities who were thinking about academic careers.
Q: Raising that particular issue, as a biologist, I neither believe in
all genetic or all environment, that in fact behavior in any other
country actually develops [unintelligible] interaction of those
aspects. And I agree with you, in fact, that it is wrong-headed to
just dismiss the biology. But to put too much weight to it is also
incredibly wrong-headed, given the fact that had people actually had
different kinds of opportunities, and different opportunities for
socialization, there is good evidence to indicate in fact that it
would have had different outcomes. I cite by way of research the
[unintelligible] project in North Carolina, which essentially shows
that, where every indicator with regard to mother's education,
socioeconomic status, et cetera, would have left a kid in a particular
place educationally, that, essentially, they are seeing totally
different outcomes with regard to performance, being referred to
special education, et cetera, so I think that there is some evidence
on that particular side. The other issue is this whole question about
objective versus subjective. I think that it is very difficult to have
anything that is basically objective, and the work of [unintelligible]
I think point out that in a case where you are actually trying to-this
case from the Swedish Medical Council, where they were trying to
identify very high-powered research opportunities for, I guess it was
post-docs by that point, that indicated that essentially that it ended
up with larger numbers of men than women. Two of the women who were
basically in the affected group were able to utilize the transparency
rules that were in place in Sweden, get access to the data, get access
to the issues, and in fact, discovered that it was not as objective as
everyone claimed, and that in fact, different standards were actually
being used for the women as well as for the men, including the men's
presence in sort of a central network, the kinds of journals that they
had to publish in to be considered at the same level, so I think that
there are pieces of research that begin to actually relate to
this-yes, there is the need to look more carefully at a lot of these
areas. I would-in addition looking at this whole question of the
quality of marginal hires-I would also like to look at the quality of
class one hires, in terms of seeing who disappoints, and what it was
that they happened to be looking at and making judgments on, and then
what the people could not deliver. So I think that there is a real
great need on both sides to begin to talk about whether or not we can
predict. I hate to use a sports metaphor, but I will. This is drawn
basically from an example from Claude Steele, where he says, he starts
by using free throws as a way of actually determining, who
should-you've got to field a basketball team, and you clearly want the
people who make ten out of ten, and you say, "Well, I may not want the
people who make zero out of ten," but what about the people who make
four out of ten. If you use that as the measure, Shaq will be left on
the sidelines.
LHS: I understand. I think you're obviously right that there's no
absolute objectivity, and you're-there's no question about that. My
own instincts actually are that you could go wrong in a number of
respects fetishizing objectivity for exactly the reasons that you
suggest. There is a very simple and straightforward methodology that
was used many years ago in the case of baseball. Somebody wrote a very
powerful article about baseball, probably in the seventies, in which
they basically said, "Look, it is true that if you look at people's
salaries, and you control for their batting averages and their
fielding averages and whatnot, whites and blacks are in the same
salary once you control. It is also true that there are no black .240
hitters in the major leagues, that the only blacks who are in the
major leagues are people who bat over .300-I'm exaggerating-and that
is exactly what you'd predict on a model of discrimination, that
because there's a natural bias against. And there's an absolute and
clear prediction. The prediction is that if there's a
discriminated-against group, that if you measure subsequent
performance, their subsequent performance will be stronger than that
of the non-discriminated-against group. And that's a simple prediction
of a theory of discrimination. And it's a testable prediction of a
theory of discrimination, and it would be a revolution, and it would
be an enormously powerful finding in this field, to demonstrate, and I
suspect there are contexts in which that can be demonstrated, but
there's a straightforward methodology, it seems to me, for testing
exactly that idea. I'm going to run out of time. But, let me take-if
people ask very short questions, I will give very short answers.
Q: What about the rest of the world. Are we keeping up? Physics,
France, very high powered women in science in top positions. Same
nature, same hormones, same ambitions we have to assume. Different
cultural, given.
LHS: Good question. Good question. I don't know much about it. My
guess is that you'll find that in most of those places, the pressure
to be high powered, to work eighty hours a week, is not the same as it
is in the United States. And therefore it is easier to balance on both
sides. But I thought about that, and I think that you'll find that's
probably at least part of the explanation.
Q: [unintelligible] because his book was referred to.
LHS: Right.
Q: I would like to make an on observation and then make a suggestion.
The observation is that of the three. There is a contradiction in your
three major observations that is the high-powered intensive need of
scientific work-that's the first-and then the ability, and then the
socialization, the social process. Would it be possible the first two
result from the last one and that math ability could be a result of
education, parenting, a lot of things. We only observe what happens,
we don't know the reason for why there's a variance. I'll give you
another thing, a suggestion. The suggestion is that one way to read
your remarks is to say maybe those are not the things we can solve
immediately. Especially as leaders of higher education because they
are just so wide, so deep, and involves all aspects of society,
institution, education, a lot of things, parenting, marriages are
institutions, for example. We could have changed the institution of
those things a lot of things we cannot change. Rather, it's not nature
and nurture, it is really pre-college versus post-college. From your
college point of view maybe those are things too late and too little
you can do but a lot of things which are determined by sources outside
the college you're in. Is that...
LHS: I think...
Q: That's a different read on your set of remarks.
LHS: I think your observation goes much more to my second point about
the abilities and the variances than it does to the first point about
what married woman....
Q: [unintelligible]
LHS: Yeah, look anything could be social, ultimately in all of that. I
think that if you look at the literature on behavioral genetics and
you look at the impact, the changed view as to what difference
parenting makes, the evidence is really quite striking and amazing. I
mean, just read Judith Rich Harris's book. It is just very striking
that people's-and her book is probably wrong and its probably more
than she says it is, and I know there are thirteen critiques and you
can argue about it and I am not certainly a leading expert on that-but
there is a lot there. And I think what it surely establishes is that
human intuition tends to substantially overestimate the role-just like
teachers overestimate their impact on their students relative to
fellow students on other students-I think we all have a tendency with
our intuitions to do it. So, you may be right, but my guess is that
there are some very deep forces here that are going to be with us for
a long time.
Q: You know, in the spirit of speaking truth to power, I'm not an
expert in this area but a lot of people in the room are, and they've
written a lot of papers in here that address ....
LHS: I've read a lot of them.
Q: And, you know, a lot of us would disagree with your hypotheses and
your premises...
LHS: Fair enough.
Q: So it's not so clear.
LHS: It's not clear at all. I think I said it wasn't clear. I was
giving you my best guess but I hope we could argue on the basis of as
much evidence as we can marshal.
Q: It's here.
LHS: No, no, no. Let me say. I have actually read that and I'm not
saying there aren't rooms to debate this in, but if somebody, but with
the greatest respect-I think there's an enormous amount one can learn
from the papers in this conference and from those two books-but if
somebody thinks that there is proof in these two books, that these
phenomenon are caused by something else, I guess I would very
respectfully have to disagree very very strongly with that. I don't
presume to have proved any view that I expressed here, but if you
think there is proof for an alternative theory, I'd want you to be
hesitant about that.
Q: Just one quick question in terms of the data. We saw this morning
lots of data showing the drop in white males entering science and
engineering, and I'm having trouble squaring that with your model of
who wants to work eighty hours a week. It's mostly people coming from
other countries that have filled that gap in terms of men versus
women.
LHS: I think there are two different things, frankly, actually, is my
guess-I'm not an expert. Somebody reported to me that-someone who is
knowledgeable-said that it is surprisingly hard to get Americans
rather than immigrants or the children of immigrants to be cardiac
surgeons. Cardiac surgeon is about prestigious, certain kind of
prestige as you can be, fact is that people want control of their
lifestyles, people want flexibility, they don't want to do it, and
it's disproportionately immigrants that want to do some of the careers
that are most demanding in terms of time and most interfering with
your lifestyle. So I think that's exactly right and I think it's
precisely the package of number of hours' work what it is, that's
leading more Americans to choose to have careers of one kind or
another in business that are less demanding of passionate thought all
the time and that includes white males as well.
Q: That's my point, that social-psychological in nature
[unintelligible].
LHS: I would actually much rather stay-yes, and then I'm on my way
out.
Q: I have no idea how you would evaluate the productivity of the
marginal hire if this person is coming into an environment where
[unintelligible] is marginal and there's [unintelligible].
LHS: You're absolutely right. You're absolutely right. I used the
term-I realized I had not spoken carefully-I used the term marginal in
the economic sense to mean, only additional, to only mean...
Q: [unintelligible].
LHS: No, to mean only the additional [unintelligible]. Yeah, obviously
[unintelligible] going to identify X is the additional hire, is the
marginal hire, the question you can ask is, you know, here is a time
when, as a consequence of an effort, there was a very substantial
increase in the number of people who were hired in a given group, what
was the observed ex post quality? And what was the observed ex post
performance? It's hard to believe that that's not a useful thing to
try to know. It may well be that one will produce powerful evidence
that the people are much better than the people who were there and
that the institutions went up in quality and that made things much
better. All I'm saying is one needs to ask the question. And as for
the groping in the kitchen, and whatnot, look, it's absolutely
important that in every university in America there be norms of
civility and proper treatment of colleagues that be absolutely
established and that that be true universally, and that's a hugely
important part of this, and that's why at Harvard we're doing a whole
set of things that are making junior faculty positions much more real
faculty positions with real mentoring, real feedback, serious searches
before the people are hired, and much greater prospects for tenure
than there ever have been before because exactly that kind of
collegiality is absolutely central to the academic enterprise.
Thank you.
More information about the paleopsych
mailing list