[Paleopsych] Reason: 10 Truths About Trade: Hard facts about offshoring, imports, and jobs

Premise Checker checker at panix.com
Wed Apr 27 19:26:07 UTC 2005


10 Truths About Trade: Hard facts about offshoring, imports, and jobs
http://www.reason.com/0407/fe.bl.truths.shtml
July 2004

[I sent this before, but it's worth reading again, since I'm still looking for 
a refutation.]

     Hard facts about offshoring, imports, and jobs.

     [6]Brink Lindsey

     Is globalization sending the best American jobs overseas? If you get
     your news from CNNs Lou Dobbs, the answer is "of course" and the
only
     real issue is how many trade restrictions should be applied to stem
     the bleeding.

     But the recent scare about "offshoring" is just the latest twist on
an
     inaccurate, decades-old complaint that global trade is stealing jobs
     and causing a "race to the bottom" in which corporations
relentlessly
     scour the world for the lowest wages and most squalid working
     conditions. China and India have replaced 1980s Japan and 1990s
Mexico
     as the most feared foreign threats to U.S. employment, and the old
     fallacy of job scarcity has once again reared its distracting head.

     The truth is cheerier. Trade is only one element in a much bigger
     picture of incessant turnover in the American labor market.
     Furthermore, the overall trend is toward more and better jobs for
     American workers. While job losses are real and sometimes very
     painful, it is important -- indeed, for the formulation of sound
     public policy, it is vital -- to distinguish between the painful
     aspects of progress and outright decline.

     Toward that end, and to counter protectionist "analysis"
masquerading
     as fact, here are 10 core truths about global trade and American
jobs.

     1. The Number of Jobs Grows With the Population

     As Figure 1 shows vividly, the total number of jobs in the American
     economy is first and foremost a function of the size of the labor
     force. As the population grows, the number of people in the work
force
     grows; then market forces absorb that supply and deploy labor to
     different sectors of the economy.

     Consider all the major events that have increased the supply of
labor
     during the last half-century: the baby boom, the surge in work force
     participation by women, and rising rates of immigration after
decades
     of restrictionist policies. Consider as well the key developments
that
     have slashed demand for certain kinds of labor: the growing
     competitiveness of foreign producers and falling U.S. barriers to
     imports; the shift by American companies toward globally integrated
     production and the consequent relocation of many operations
overseas;
     the deregulation of the transportation, energy, and
telecommunications
     industries and the wrenching restructuring that followed; and, most
     important, the many waves of labor-saving technological innovations,
     from the containerization that replaced longshoremen to the dial
     phones that replaced switchboard operators to the factory-floor
robots
     that replaced assembly-line workers to the automatic teller machines
     that replaced bank tellers.

     Yet in the face of all this flux, no chronic shortage of jobs has
ever
     materialized. Over those tumultuous five decades, a growing economy
     and functioning labor markets were all that was needed to
accommodate
     huge shifts in labor supply and demand. Now and in the future, sound
     macroeconomic policies and continued flexibility in labor markets
will
     suffice to generate increasing employment, notwithstanding the rise
of
     China and India and the march of digitization.

     2. Jobs Churn Constantly

     The steady increase in total employment masks the frenetic dynamism
of
     the U.S. labor market. Gross changes -- total new positions added,
     total existing positions eliminated -- are much greater in
magnitude.
     Large numbers of jobs are being shed constantly, even in good times.
     Total employment continues to increase only because even larger
     numbers of jobs are being created.

     According to economist Brad DeLong, a weekly figure of 360,000 new
     unemployment insurance claims is actually consistent with a stable
     unemployment rate. In other words, when the unemployment rate holds
     steady -- that is, total employment grows fast enough to absorb the
     ongoing increase in the labor force -- some 18.7 million people will
     lose their jobs and file unemployment insurance claims during the
     course of a single year. Meanwhile, even more people will get new
     jobs.

     More detailed and dramatic evidence of job turnover can be found in
     Table 1. According to data compiled by the Department of Labors
Bureau
     of Labor Statistics, total private-sector employment rose by 17.8
     million between 1993 and 2002. To produce that healthy net increase,
a
     breathtaking total of 327.7 million jobs were added, while 309.9
     million jobs were lost. In other words, for every one net new
     private-sector job created during that period, 18.4 gross job
     additions had to offset 17.4 gross job losses.

     In light of those facts, it is impossible to give credence to claims
     that job losses in this or that sector constitute a looming
     catastrophe for the enormous and dynamic U.S. economy as a whole. It
     is as inevitable that some companies and industries will shrink as
it
     is that others will expand. Localized challenges and problems should
     not be confused with national crises.

     3. Challenging, High-Paying Jobs Are Becoming More Plentiful, Not
Less

     The ongoing growth in total employment is frequently dismissed on
the
     ground that most of the new positions being created are low-paying,
     dead-end "McJobs." The facts show otherwise.

     Managerial and specialized professional jobs have grown rapidly,
     nearly doubling between 1983 and 2002, from 23.6 million to 42.5
     million. These challenging, high-paying positions have jumped from
     23.4 percent of total employment to 31.1 percent.

     And these high-quality jobs will continue growing in the years to
     come. According to projections for 2002-12 prepared by the Bureau of
     Labor Statistics, management, business, financial, and professional
     positions will grow from 43.2 million to 52 million, increasing from
     30 percent of total employment to 31.5 percent.

     4. "Deindustrialization" Is a Myth

     Opponents of open markets frequently claim that unshielded exposure
to
     foreign competition is destroying the U.S. manufacturing base. That
     charge is flatly untrue. Figure 2 sets the record straight: Between
     1980 and 2003, American manufacturing output climbed a dizzying 93
     percent. Yes, production fell during the recent recession, but it is
     now recovering: the industrial production index for manufacturing
rose
     2.2 percent in 2003.

     It is true that manufacturings share of gross domestic product has
     been declining gradually over time -- from 27 percent in 1960 to
13.9
     percent in 2002. The percentage of workers employed in manufacturing
     likewise has been falling, from 28.4 percent to 11.7 percent during
     the same period. But the primary cause of these trends is the
superior
     productivity of American manufacturers. As shown in Figure 3, output
     per hour in the overall nonfarm business sector rose 50 percent
     between 1980 and 2002; by contrast, manufacturing output per hour
shot
     up 103 percent. In other words, goods are getting cheaper and
cheaper
     relative to services. Since this faster productivity growth has not
     been matched by a corresponding increase in demand for manufactured
     goods, the result is that Americans are spending relatively less on
     manufactures. Accordingly, manufacturings shrinking share of the
     overall economy is actually a sign of American manufacturing
prowess.

     Exactly the same phenomenon has played out over a longer period in
     agriculture. In 1870, 47.6 percent of total employment was in
farming.
     By 2002 the figure had fallen to 1.7 percent. In the future,
     manufacturing will in all likelihood continue down the trail blazed
by
     agriculture. People who bemoan this prospect dont recognize economic
     progress when they see it.

     International trade has had only a modest effect on manufacturings
     declining share of the economy. It is true that imports displace
some
     domestic production. On the other hand, exports boost sales for
     American manufacturers. The U.S. has been running a manufacturing
     trade deficit in recent years, but even if trade had been in balance
     between 1960 and 2002 the manufacturing share of GDP still would
have
     fallen sharply, down to an estimated 16 percent (as opposed to the
     actual 13.9 percent). Innovation creates a steady, relentless drop
in
     manufacturings share of economic activity.

     5. Imports Have Not Been a Major Cause of Recent Manufacturing Job
     Losses

     Employment in the manufacturing sector has taken a beating in recent
     years. Between 1965 and 1990, the total number of manufacturing jobs
     fluctuated in a stable band between 16 million and 20 million;
during
     the 1990s, the upper limit dropped to around 18 million; but between
     July 2000 and October 2003 jobs plummeted 16 percent, from 17.32
     million to 14.56 million.

     Although the losses have been severe, the charge that those jobs
were
     eliminated by foreign competition simply doesnt square with the
facts.
     As shown in Table 2, manufacturing imports rose only 0.6 percent
     between 2000 and 2003. By contrast, manufacturing exports fell by
9.6
     percent. In other words, during this period the drop in exports
     accounted for 91 percent of the growth in the manufacturing trade
     deficit.

     Accordingly, imports played at best a trivial role in the recent
sharp
     decline in manufacturing employment. The main culprit was the
     worsening domestic market for manufactures during the recent
recession
     -- in particular, a big drop in business investment. Between the
     fourth quarter of 2000 and the third quarter of 2002, total fixed
     nonresidential investment fell by 14 percent. Looking abroad, it was
     softening overseas markets, much more than stiffening import
pressure,
     that added further downward pressure on domestic manufacturing jobs.
     Consequently, anti-trade activists who cite manufacturing job losses
     as a reason to turn away from trade liberalization couldnt be more
     wrong. Expanding overseas markets and commercial opportunities for
     American exporters would be a shot in the arm for manufacturing
     employment.

     6. "Offshoring" Is Not a Threat to High-Tech Employment

     In recent months, historical fears about vanishing manufacturing
jobs
     have been compounded by growing anxiety about trade-related job
losses
     in the service sector. Advances in information and communications
     technologies now make it possible for many jobs -- from customer
     service calls to software development -- to be performed anywhere.

     In particular, the offshoring of information technology (I.T.) jobs
to
     India and other low-wage countries has received a flurry of
attention.
     According to a survey of hiring managers conducted by the
Information
     Technology Association of America, 12 percent of I.T. companies
     already have outsourced some operations abroad. As for future
trends,
     Forrester Research predicted in a widely cited study that 3.3
million
     white-collar jobs -- including 1.7 million back-office positions and
     473,000 I.T. jobs -- will move overseas between 2000 and 2015.

     Adding to the fear, I.T. employment has experienced a significant
     recent decline. In 2002, according to the Department of Commerce,
the
     total number of I.T.-related jobs stood at 5.95 million, down from a
     2000 peak of 6.47 million. Although some of those jobs were lost
     because of offshoring, the major culprits were the slowdown in
demand
     for I.T. services after the Y2K buildup, followed by the dot-com
     collapse and the broader recession. Moreover, it should be
remembered
     that the recent drop in employment took place after a dramatic
     buildup. In 1994, 1.19 million people were employed as mathematical
     and computer scientists. By 2000 that figure had jumped to 2.07
     million -- a 74 percent increase. As of 2002, the figure had
decreased
     only slightly to 2.03 million, still 71 percent higher than in 1994.

     Despite the trend toward offshoring, I.T.-related employment is
     expected to see healthy increases in the years to come. According to
     Department of Labor projections, the total number of jobs in
computer
     and mathematical occupations will jump from 3.02 million in 2002 to
     4.07 million in 2012 -- a 35 percent increase. Of the 30 specific
     occupations projected to grow fastest during those 10 years, seven
are
     computer-related. (See Figure 4 for the fastest-growing
     computer-related occupations.) Thus, the recent downturn in I.T. is
     likely only a temporary break in a larger trend of robust job
growth.

     The wild claims that offshoring will gut employment in the I.T.
sector
     are totally at odds with reality. I.T. job losses projected by
     Forrester amount to fewer than 32,000 per year -- relatively modest
     attrition in the context of 6 million I.T. jobs. These losses,
     meanwhile, will be offset by newly created jobs as computer and
     mathematical occupations continue to boom. The doomsayers are
     confusing a cyclical downturn with a permanent trend.

     7. Globalization of Services Creates Enormous Opportunity for
American
     Industry

     Offshoring of I.T. services to India and elsewhere has been made
     possible by ongoing advances in computer and communications
     technologies. If those advances indeed pose a threat to domestic
I.T.
     services industries, then it should be possible to trace the
emergence
     of that threat in trade statistics, since offshoring registers as an
     increase in services imports.

     Yet the fact is that the U.S. runs a trade surplus precisely in the
     I.T. services most directly affected by offshoring. In the
categories
     of "computer and data processing services" and "database and other
     information services," American exports rose from $2.4 billion in
1995
     to $5.4 billion in 2002, while imports increased from $0.3 billion
to
     $1.2 billion. Thus, the U.S. trade surplus in these services has
     expanded from $2.1 billion to $4.2 billion.

     Meanwhile, the same technological advances that have given rise to
     offshoring are facilitating the international provision of all kinds
     of services -- banking, accounting, legal assistance, engineering,
     medicine, and so on. The United States is a major exporter of
services
     generally and runs a sizable trade surplus in services. In 2002, for
     example, service exports accounted for 30 percent of all U.S.
exports
     and exceeded service imports by $64.8 billion. Accordingly, the
     increasing ability to provide services remotely is a commercial boon
     to many U.S.-based service industries. Although some jobs are
     doubtless at risk, the same trends that make offshoring possible are
     creating new opportunities, and new jobs, throughout the domestic
     economy.

     8. Offshoring Creates New Jobs and Boosts Economic Growth

     Although offshoring does eliminate jobs, it also yields important
     benefits. To the extent that companies can reduce costs by shifting
     certain operations overseas, they are increasing productivity. The
     process of competition ultimately passes the resulting cost savings
on
     to consumers, which then spurs demand for other goods and services.
     Whether caused by the introduction of new technology or by new ways
to
     organize work, productivity increases translate into economic growth
     and rising overall living standards.

     In particular, offshoring encourages the diffusion of I.T.
throughout
     the American economy. According to Catherine Mann at the Institute
for
     International Economics, globalized production of I.T. hardware --
     that is, the offshoring of computer-related manufacturing -- has
     accounted for 10 percent to 30 percent of the drop in hardware
prices.
     The resulting increase in productivity encouraged the rapid spread
of
     computer use and thereby added some $230 billion in cumulative
     additional GDP between 1995 and 2002.

     Offshoring offers the potential to take a similar bite out of prices
     for I.T. software and services. Those price reductions will promote
     the further spread of I.T. and new business processes that take
     advantage of cheap technology. As Mann notes, health services and
     construction are two large and important sectors that today feature
     low I.T. intensity (as measured by I.T. equipment per worker) and
     below-average productivity growth. Diffusion of I.T. into these and
     other sectors could prompt a new round of productivity growth such
as
     that provoked by the globalization of hardware production during the
     1990s.

     9. The Digital Revolution Has Been Eliminating White-Collar Jobs for
     Many Years

     The attention now being paid to offshoring creates the impression
that
     it is an utterly unprecedented phenomenon. But the very same
     technological advances that are making offshoring possible have been
     eliminating large numbers of white-collar jobs for many years now.

     The diffusion of I.T. throughout the economy has caused major
shakeups
     in the job market during the last decade. Voicemail has replaced
     receptionists; back-office record-keeping and other clerical jobs
have
     been supplanted by computers; layers of middle management have been
     eliminated by better internal communications systems. In all these
     cases, jobs are not simply being transferred overseas; they are
being
     consigned to oblivion by automation and the resulting reorganization
     of work processes.

     The increased churn in white-collar jobs shows up in the Department
of
     Labors statistics on displaced long-tenured workers, defined as
     workers who have lost jobs they held for three years or more (Figure
     5). During the 1981--82 recession blue-collar workers bore the brunt
     of long-tenured displacement, but by 1991-92 more than half of the
     long-held jobs lost were white-collar. Even in the better years that
     followed, innovation and job churn continued to displace
white-collar
     workers at a higher rate than during the 1981-82 recession.

     Offshoring is merely the latest manifestation of a well-established
     process. The only difference is that, with offshoring, I.T. is
     facilitating the transfer of jobs overseas. In either case, domestic
     jobs are lost to technological progress and rising productivity. Why
     is this downside taken in stride when jobs are eliminated entirely
yet
     considered unbearable when the jobs are taken as hand-me-downs by
     Indians and other foreigners?

     10. Fears That the U.S. Economy Is Running Out of Jobs Are Nothing
New

     Because of the recent recession, the U.S. economy has suffered from
a
     shortage of jobs, as evidenced by the rise in the unemployment rate.
     There is a natural temptation under these conditions to fear that
this
     temporary setback is the beginning of some permanent reversal of
     fortune, that the shortage of jobs is here to stay and will only
grow
     worse.

     To calm such fears, it is useful to recall that similar anxieties
have
     surfaced before. Again and again, over many decades, cyclical
     downturns in the economy have prompted predictions of permanent job
     shortages. And each time, those predictions were belied by the
ensuing
     economic expansion.

     Back in the 1930s, the brutal and persistent unemployment caused by
     the Great Depression gave rise to theories of "secular stagnation."
A
     number of leading economists -- including, most prominently,
Harvards
     Alvin Hansen -- argued that declining population growth and the
     increasing "maturity" of the industrial economy meant that we could
no
     longer rely on private-sector job creation to provide full
employment.
     The stagnationist thesis eventually fell out of fashion once the
     postwar economic boom gathered steam.

     The return of higher unemployment in the late 1950s and early 60s
led
     to a revival of the stagnationist fallacy, this time in the guise of
     an "automation crisis." The ongoing progress of factory automation,
     combined with the growing visibility of electronic computers, led
many
     Americans to believe, once again, that the economy was running out
of
     jobs. During the 1960 presidential campaign, John F. Kennedy, who
ran
     on a pledge to "get the country moving again," warned that
automation
     "carries the dark menace of industrial dislocation, increasing
     unemployment, and deepening poverty." The American Foundation on
     Automation and Unemployment, a joint industry-labor group created in
     1962, claimed breathlessly that automation was "second only to the
     possibility of the hydrogen bomb" in its challenge to Americas
     economic future. For the record, U.S. employment in 1962 stood at
66.7
     million jobs -- roughly half the current total.

     In the early 1980s, the coincidence of a severe recession and a
string
     of competitive successes by Japanese producers at the expense of
     high-profile American industries sparked predictions of the imminent
     "deindustrialization" of the American economy. As financier Felix
     Rohatyn complained, in a fashion typical of the time, "We cannot
     become a nation of short-order cooks and saleswomen, Xerox-machine
     operators and messenger boys....These jobs are a weak basis for the
     economy." Along similar lines, Sen. Lloyd Bentsen (D-Texas) fretted
     that "American workers will end up like the people in the biblical
     village who were condemned to be hewers of wood and drawers of
     waters." It should be noted that U.S. manufacturing output has
roughly
     doubled since 1982.

     In the early 1990s, another recession resulted in yet another job
     shortage scare. Ross Perot won 19 percent of the presidential vote
in
     1992 with a campaign that, among other things, railed against the
     "giant sucking sound" of jobs lost to Mexico and other foreign
     countries. That same year, Pulitzer Prize-winning journalists Donald
     L. Barlett and James B. Steele published a widely discussed
jeremiad,
     America: What Went Wrong?, about the decline and fall of the
countrys
     middle class. That hand wringing was followed in short order by one
of
     the most remarkable expansions in American economic history.

     Again and again, serious and influential voices have raised the cry
     that the sky is falling. It never does. The root of their error is
     always the same: confusing a temporary, cyclical downturn with a
     permanent reduction in the economys job-creating capacity.

     In recent years, many Americans have lost their jobs and suffered
     hardship as a result. Many more have worried that their jobs would
be
     next. There is no point in denying these hard realities, but just as
     surely there is no point in blowing them out of proportion. The U.S.
     economy is not running out of good jobs; it is merely coming out of
a
     recession. And regardless of whether economic times are good or bad,
     some amount of job turnover is an inescapable fact of life in a
     dynamic market economy.

     This fact cannot be wished away by blaming foreigners, and it cannot
     be undone by trade restrictions. The innovation and productivity
     increases that render some jobs obsolete are also the source of new
     wealth and rising living standards. Embracing change and its
     unavoidable disruptions is the only way to secure the continuing
gains
     of economic advancement. -------------------------------------

     Brink Lindsey is a senior fellow at the Cato Institute and director
of
     its Center for Trade Policy Studies. He is the author of Against the
     Dead Hand: The Uncertain Struggle for Global Capitalism (John Wiley
&
     Sons). This article is based on a longer paper published by the Cato
     Institute, available [7]online (PDF) . Sources for all the figures
in
     this article are available in the original Cato study.

References

     6. mailto:blindsey at cato.org
     7. http://www.freetrade.org/pubs/briefs/tbp-019.pdf



More information about the paleopsych mailing list