[Paleopsych] NYT Mag: (Freakonomics) The Economy of Desire
Premise Checker
checker at panix.com
Sun Dec 11 03:06:09 UTC 2005
The Economy of Desire
http://select.nytimes.com/preview/2005/12/11/magazine/1124989462701.html
[A good primer.]
By STEPHEN J. DUBNER and STEVEN D. LEVITT
Analyzing a Sex Survey
What is a price?
Unless you're an economist, you probably think of a price as
simply the amount you pay for a given thing - the number of
dollars you surrender for, let's say, Sunday brunch at your
favorite neighborhood restaurant. But to an economist, price is
a much broader concept. The 20 minutes you spend waiting for a
table is part of the price. So, too, is any nutritional
downside of the meal itself: a cheeseburger, as the economist
Kevin Murphy has calculated, costs $2.50 more than a salad in
long-term health implications. There are moral and social costs
to tally as well - for instance, the look of scorn delivered by
your vegan dining partner as you order the burger. While the
restaurant's menu may list the price of the cheeseburger at
$7.95, that is clearly just the beginning.
The most fundamental rule of economics is that a rise in price
leads to less quantity demanded. This holds true for a
restaurant meal, a real-estate deal, a college education or
just about anything else you can think of. When the price of an
item rises, you buy less of it (which is not to say, of course,
that you want less of it).
But what about sex? Sex, that most irrational of human
pursuits, couldn't possibly respond to rational price theory,
could it?
Outside of a few obvious situations, we generally don't think
about sex in terms of prices. Prostitution is one such
situation; courtship is another: certain men seem to consider
an expensive dinner a prudent investment in pursuit of a sexual
dividend.
But how might price changes affect sexual behavior? And might
those changes have something to tell us about the nature of sex
itself?
Here is a stark example: A man who is sent to prison finds that
the price of sex with a woman has spiked - talk about a supply
shortage - and he becomes much more likely to start having sex
with men. The reported prevalence of oral sex among affluent
American teenagers would also seem to illustrate price theory:
because of the possibility of disease or pregnancy, intercourse
is expensive - and it has come to be seen by some teenagers as
an unwanted and costly pledge of commitment. In this light,
oral sex may be viewed as a cheaper alternative.
In recent decades, we have witnessed the most exorbitant new
price associated with sex: the H.I.V. virus. Because AIDS is
potentially deadly and because it can be spread relatively
easily by sex between two men, the onset of AIDS in the early
1980's caused a significant increase in the price of gay sex.
Andrew Francis, a graduate student in economics at the
University of Chicago, has tried to affix a dollar figure to
this change. Setting the value of an American life at $2
million, Francis calculated that in terms of AIDS-related
mortality, it cost $1,923.75 in 1992 (the peak of the AIDS
crisis) for a man to have unprotected sex once with a random
gay American man versus less than $1 with a random woman. While
the use of a condom greatly reduces the risk of contracting
AIDS, a condom is, of course, yet another cost associated with
sex. In a study of Mexican prostitution, the Berkeley economist
Paul Gertler and two co-authors showed that when a client
requested sex without a condom, a prostitute was typically paid
a 24 percent premium over her standard fee.
Francis, in a draft paper titled "The Economics of Sexuality,"
tries to go well beyond dollar figures. He puts forth an
empirical argument that may fundamentally challenge how people
think about sex.
As with any number of behaviors that social scientists try to
measure, sex is a tricky subject. But Francis discovered a data
set that offered some intriguing possibilities. The National
Health and Social Life Survey, sponsored by the U.S. government
and a handful of foundations, asked almost 3,500 people a
rather astonishing variety of questions about sex: the
different sexual acts received and performed and with whom and
when; questions about sexual preference and identity; whether
they knew anyone with AIDS. As with any self-reported data,
there was the chance that the survey wasn't reliable, but it
had been designed to ensure anonymity and generate honest
replies.
The survey was conducted in 1992, when the disease was much
less treatable than it is today. Francis first looked to see if
there was a positive correlation between having a friend with
AIDS and expressing a preference for homosexual sex. As he
expected, there was. "After all, people pick their friends," he
says, "and homosexuals are more likely to have other
homosexuals as friends."
But you don't get to pick your family. So Francis next looked
for a correlation between having a relative with AIDS and
expressing a homosexual preference. This time, for men, the
correlation was negative. This didn't seem to make sense. Many
scientists believe that a person's sexual orientation is
determined before birth, a function of genetic fate. If
anything, people in the same family should be more likely to
share the same orientation. "Then I realized, Oh, my God, they
were scared of AIDS," Francis says.
Francis zeroed in on this subset of about 150 survey
respondents who had a relative with AIDS. Because the survey
compiled these respondents' sexual histories as well as their
current answers about sex, it allowed Francis to measure,
albeit crudely, how their lives may have changed as a result of
having seen up close the costly horrors of AIDS.
Here's what he found: Not a single man in the survey who had a
relative with AIDS said he had had sex with a man in the
previous five years; not a single man in that group declared
himself to be attracted to men or to consider himself
homosexual. Women in that group also shunned sex with men. For
them, rates of recent sex with women and of declaring
homosexual identity and attraction were more than twice as high
as those who did not have a relative with AIDS.
Because the sample size was so small - simple chance suggests
that no more than a handful of men in a group that size would
be attracted to men - it is hard to reach definitive
conclusions from the survey data. (Obviously, not every single
man changes his sexual behavior or identity when a relative
contracts AIDS.) But taken as a whole, the numbers in Francis's
study suggest that there may be a causal effect here - that
having a relative with AIDS may change not just sexual behavior
but also self-reported identity and desire.
In other words, sexual preference, while perhaps largely
predetermined, may also be subject to the forces more typically
associated with economics than biology. If this turns out to be
true, it would change the way that everyone - scientists,
politicians, theologians - thinks about sexuality. But it
probably won't much change the way economists think. To them,
it has always been clear: whether we like it or not, everything
has its price.
Stephen J. Dubner and Steven D. Levitt are the authors of
"Freakonomics: A Rogue Economist Explores the Hidden Side of
Everything." More information on the academic research behind
this column is at [3]www.freakonomics.com.
More information about the paleopsych
mailing list