[Paleopsych] Ecnomist: (Posner) American intellectuals: The new phrenology

Premise Checker checker at panix.com
Thu Feb 3 20:12:48 UTC 2005


American intellectuals: The new phrenology 
http://www.economist.com/PrinterFriendly.cfm?Story_ID=975532
2.2.7 (note date)

    Public Intellectuals: A Study of Decline.
    By Richard A. Posner.
    Harvard University Press; 448 pages; $29.95 and £20.50

    "I'M NOT a donkey, and I don't have a field." So scoffed Max Weber, a
    great German social thinker, when a faculty non-entity criticised him
    for writing outside his discipline. The academic division of labour
    has come on apace since Weber's day (he died in 1920), and hardly a
    year has passed when someone from the cultural-decline crowd did not
    decry the narrowing of scholarship and bemoan what they took for its
    consequence: the death of the free-ranging intellectual.

    This concern is not foolish. Who does not wish that the worlds and
    sub-worlds of science, public affairs and humanities could better talk
    to one another? Who does not applaud those valuable souls who can move
    between these worlds with even a hint of grace or plausibility?

    Richard Posner, an American federal-appeals judge, law professor and
    prolific author, puts a new spin on these old anxieties. The trouble
    with the (mainly American) intellectuals that preoccupy him is not, in
    his view, that they are dying, but that they are not any good.

    He starts off by ruling out what most of us would take as archetypal
    intellectuals: scientists who explain science to lay people (eg,
    Steven Weinberg), philosophers with an influential vision of society
    (eg, John Rawls or Robert Nozick) and literary intellectuals of high
    Bohemia (eg, Susan Sontag). No, his public intellectuals are really
    pundits: people who opine about issues of the day on television or in
    newspaper columns. On the theory that if it's real it must be
    countable, he ranks what he calls the top 100 on the basis of
    scholarly citations, media mentions and web hits.

    Though some of his pundits (such as Henry Kissinger) have escaped from
    government, most are moonlighters from universities or think-tanks. As
    scholars, he tells us, they know much about little; as media
    egg-heads, they must talk about almost anything. Naturally, they fall
    on their faces: their stock-in-trade is prediction and some of their
    forecasts (he doesn't say what proportion) turn out to be wrong.

    There are, he adds, too many of them. The supply of commentators
    outruns demand, and the quality of comment is therefore falling. To
    improve things, he suggests that public intellectuals should pay more
    attention to social (particularly economic) realities, spare us their
    value judgments and post their columns on university websites (where
    colleagues will supposedly spot and correct their errors).

    What are we to make of this extraordinary construction, with its
    artificial-vanilla-flavour assumptions? Mr Posner was a founder of the
    law-and-economics movement, an influential view of law which, crudely,
    recommends economic efficiency as the test of fair allocation. Yet
    since writing a law-and-economics textbook he has wandered ever
    farther afield.

    Like Mr Posner himself, "Public Intellectuals" is both brilliant and
    maddening. His knowledge and interests are wide. He is, in a sense, a
    classic intellectual. His topic, the health of public debate, matters.
    A dry, factual take on America's commentariat is--or would have
    been--welcome. But he is here too partisan, too hurried and too driven
    by the conclusions he wants to reach. In the end, the only
    intellectuals he does not scorn, you feel, are those who share his
    reductive and utilitarian outlook. Being a serious intellectual is
    harder than it looks. That is Mr Posner's point. But need he have
    illustrated it with this book?


More information about the paleopsych mailing list