[Paleopsych] LRB: (Jared Diamond) Partha Dasgupta: Bottlenecks
Premise Checker
checker at panix.com
Wed May 18 22:49:16 UTC 2005
Partha Dasgupta: Bottlenecks
http://www.lrb.co.uk/v27/n10/print/dasg01_.html
London Review of Books Vol. 27 No. 10 dated 19 May 2005
Collapse: How Societies Choose to Fail or Survive by Jared Diamond
Allen Lane, 575 pp, £20.00
Are our dealings with nature sustainable? Can we expect world economic
growth to continue for the foreseeable future? Should we be confident
that our knowledge and skills will increase in ways that will lessen
our reliance on nature despite our growing numbers and rising economic
activity?
These questions have been debated for decades. If the debate has
become increasingly shrill, it is because two opposing ways of looking
at the world continue to shape it. If, on the one hand, we look at
specific examples of natural assets (fresh water, ocean fisheries, the
atmosphere as a carbon `sink': ecosystems generally), there is
convincing evidence that at the rate at which we currently exploit
them, they are very likely to change character for the worse, with
very little warning. On the other hand, if we study historical trends
in the price of marketed resources, or improvements in life
expectancy, or recorded growth in incomes in regions that are
currently rich or on the way to becoming so, the scarcity of resources
would appear not yet to have bitten us. If you were to point out that
there are acute scarcities in the troubled nations of sub-Saharan
Africa, those whose perspective is ecological will tell you that
people living in the world's poorest regions are poor because they
face acute scarcities relative to their numbers; while those whose
perspective is economic will argue that people experience scarcities
precisely because they are poor.
You may think that a study of past societies could throw some light on
the question. Most people have heard about the marked decline in the
population of Easter Island some three centuries ago; they may know,
too, of the pueblos abandoned by the Anasazi in the south-west United
States eight hundred years ago, and of the disappearance of the Maya
of the southern Yucatán a thousand years ago. They are dimly aware
that these events had something to do with mismanagement of the local
environment, reinforced in some cases by prolonged droughts. But the
same people also know that the civilisations of China and India have
evolved for about 5000 years and 3500 years respectively, and that
neither is about to say goodbye. So what were the differences between
the civilisations that disappeared and those that adapted more or less
successfully to changing circumstances over the millennia? To say that
the societies that have survived have done so because they managed
their habitats well, maintained profitable relationships with their
neighbours and prevented their members from killing one another, isn't
really to say anything: the survival of those societies itself proves
all that. We have to know what the successful ones did in order to
avoid the mistakes of those that went under. We would then want to
know what those societies that have enjoyed material progress in
recent centuries did that was not only not wrong, but may even have
been right.
Jared Diamond, a professor of geography in California, looks for
answers to these big questions by examining the societies that
collapsed. The body of his book contains accounts of four such
societies: the Easter Islanders; the Anasazi; the Mayans; and the
Norse in Greenland, who died out six hundred years ago. Diamond
demonstrates that the proximate cause of each collapse was ecological
devastation brought about, broadly speaking, by one or more of the
following: deforestation and habitat destruction; soil degradation
(erosion, salinisation and fertility decline); water management
problems; over-hunting; over-fishing; population growth; increased per
capita impact on the environment; and the impact of exotic species on
native species of plants and animals. As might be expected, the
relative importance of these factors differs from case to case.
Diamond's case studies have a thoroughness appropriate to the moral
seriousness of his inquiry. He traces the way, step by tragic step,
each of those long-dead societies, as their circumstances changed,
made choices that led to their demise. In a moving account of the
Norse in Greenland, for example, he shows that there was seemingly
nothing wrong with their society. They had brought with them a devout
and orderly set of practices relating them to God, to one another and
to nature as they had known it in southern Norway. As Diamond
discovers, the immigrants possessed an enormous amount of what today
is known as `social capital'. And in that lay the source of their
eventual collapse; for in their determination to maintain cultural
coherence in a foreign environment, they made no attempt to learn from
the native inhabitants - the Inuit - about the local ecology and the
reasons the latter relied on fish and seals for sustenance. The
immigrants' culture had been built instead on cattle, crops and wooden
houses. And in choosing to pursue their previous way of life in a
fragile, alien landscape, they effectively signed their own death
warrant. The Norse in fact died of starvation. This is history as
geography, and it is deep and heady stuff.
In his search for the root cause of each collapse, Diamond deems no
item of information innocuous, no evidence too awkward for
consideration. He treats his raw materials like pieces in a jigsaw
puzzle - written records, archaeological remains, oral history,
palaeontological imprints - and places them against the broad canvas
of those societies' geography. He sifts through them to reach the most
plausible reconstruction of what happened in the distant past. It is
detective work of great skill and integrity. Some might wonder whether
we need two hundred pages of analysis to reach an understanding of
these collapses, but I find Diamond's obsession with detail wholly
understandable. When you embark on a project of such scope as this,
the urge to dig and then poke around some more to check what else
there might be is irresistible.
Diamond's reading of the collapses is original, for nature doesn't
figure prominently in contemporary intellectual sensibilities.
Economists, for example, have moved steadily away from seeing location
as a determinant of human experience. Indeed, economic progress is
seen as a release from location's grip on our lives. Economists stress
that investment and growth in knowledge have reduced transport costs
over the centuries. They observe, too, the role of industrialisation
in ironing out the effects on societies of geographical difference,
such as differences in climate, soil quality, distance from navigable
water and, concomitantly, local ecosystems. Modern theories of
economic development dismiss geography as a negligible factor in
progress. The term `globalisation' is itself a sign that location per
se doesn't matter; which may be why contemporary societies are
obsessed with cultural survival and are on the whole dismissive of our
need to discover how to survive ecologically.
Diamond believes that the risk of collapses such as those experienced
by earlier societies should be a matter for increasing concern today.
To demonstrate why, he describes how Rwanda's collapse as a society
was brought about by unprecedented population growth in a subsistence
economy operating in a fragile ecosystem. He also offers a natural
history of China and Australia and the impact their populations are
now having on their ecosystems. By his reckoning, the situation today
is worse than it has ever been: as well as the old dangers of
deforestation and so forth, we now have to deal with anthropogenic
climate change, the accumulation of toxic chemicals, energy shortages
and a near-full use of the Earth's photosynthetic capacity. The
concluding chapters of the book are devoted to speculations on the
contemporary human condition, responses to dismissals of the concerns
of environmentalists by sceptics, and a meditation on our hopes and
the perils we face. Which is when the book skids and becomes a mess.
Diamond thinks that in order to demonstrate that mankind is currently
engaged in unsustainable economic activity, it's enough to offer a
sample of the insults modern economies have been inflicting on nature.
Thus he reports a case of deforestation here, increased pesticide
run-off there, loss of biota somewhere else and carbon emissions
everywhere. But we have been travelling that route for nearly five
decades now: environmentalists have routinely pointed to the damage
modern economic activity inflicts. Moreover, in recent years such
environmental scientists as Paul Ehrlich, Edward Wilson and, most
recently, Gretchen Daily, Harold Mooney and Walter Reid, have spoken
out while taking far greater care with details and qualifications than
Diamond appears to believe is necessary.
The more important reason why Diamond's rhetoric doesn't play well any
longer is that it presents only one side of the balance-sheet: it
ignores the human benefits that accompany environmental damage. You
build a road, but that destroys part of the local ecosystem; there is
both a cost and a benefit and you have to weigh them up. Diamond shows
no sign of wanting to look at both sides of the ledger, and his
responses to environmental sceptics take the form of `Yes, but . . .'
If someone were to point out that chemical fertilisers have increased
food production dozens of times over, he would reply: `Yes, but they
are a drain on fresh water, and what about all that phosphorus
run-off?' Diamond is like a swimmer who competes in a race using only
one arm. `In caring for the health of our surroundings, just as of our
bodies,' he writes at one point, `it is cheaper and preferable to
avoid getting sick than to try to cure illnesses after they have
developed' - which sounds wise, but is simply misleading bombast.
Technology brings out the worst in him. At one point he claims that
`all of our current problems are unintended negative consequences of
our existing technology,' to which I felt like shouting in
exasperation that perhaps at some times, in some places, a few of the
unintended consequences of our existing technology have been
beneficial. Reading Diamond you would think our ancestors should all
have remained hunter-gatherers in Africa, co-evolving with the native
flora and fauna, and roaming the wilds in search of wild berries and
the occasional piece of meat.
Here I should put my cards on the table. I am an economist who shares
Diamond's worries, but I think he has failed to grasp both the way in
which information about particular states of affairs gets transmitted
(however imperfectly) in modern decentralised economies - via economic
signals such as prices, demand, product quality and migration - and
the way increases in the scarcity of resources can itself act to spur
innovations that ease those scarcities. Without a sympathetic
understanding of economic mechanisms, it isn't possible to offer
advice on the interactions between nature and the human species.
Here is an example of what I mean. Forests loom large in Diamond's
case studies. As deforestation was the proximate cause of the Easter
Islanders' demise, he offers an extended, contrasting account of the
way a deforested Japan succeeded, in the early 18th century, in
averting total disaster by regenerating its forests. Now consider
another island: England. Deforestation here began under the Romans,
and by Elizabethan times the price of timber had begun to rise
ominously. In the mid-18th century what people saw across the
landscape in England wasn't trees, but stone rows separating
agricultural fields. The noted economic historian Brinley Thomas
argued that it was because timber had become so scarce that a lengthy
search began among inventors and tinkerers for an effective coal-based
energy source. By Thomas's reckoning, the defining moment of the
Industrial Revolution should be located in 1784, when Henry Cort's
process for manufacturing iron was first successfully deployed. His
analysis would suggest that England became the centre of the
Industrial Revolution not because it had abundant energy but because
it was running out of energy. France, in contrast, didn't need to find
a substitute energy source: it was covered in forests and therefore
lost out. I'm not able to judge the plausibility of Thomas's thesis -
there would appear to be almost as many views about the origins,
timing and location of the Industrial Revolution (granting there was
one) as there are economic historians - but the point remains that
scarcities lead individuals and societies to search for ways out,
which often means discovering alternatives. Diamond is dismissive of
the possibility of our finding such alternatives in the future
because, as he would have it, we are about to come up against natural
bottlenecks. We should be persuaded by the evidence that has been
gathered over the years by environmental scientists that he is right,
but simply telling us that we are about to hit bottlenecks won't do,
because environmental sceptics would reply that discovering
alternatives is the way to avoid them.
If the future is translucent at best, what about studying the recent
past to see how the human species has been doing? The question then
arises: how should we recognise the trade-offs between a society's
present and future needs for goods and services? To put it another
way, how should we conceptualise sustainable development? The
Brundtland Commission Report of 1987 defined it as `development that
meets the needs of the present without compromising the ability of
future generations to meet their own needs'. In other words,
sustainable development requires that each generation bequeath to its
successor at least as large a productive base as it inherited. But how
is a generation to judge whether it is leaving behind an adequate
productive base for its successor?
An economy's productive base consists of its capital assets and its
institutions. Ecological economists have recently shown that the
correct measure of that base is wealth. They have shown, too, that in
estimating wealth, not only is the value of manufactured assets to be
included (buildings, machinery, roads), but also `human' capital
(knowledge, skills health), natural capital (ecosystems, minerals,
fossil fuels), and institutions (government, civil society, the rule
of law). So development is sustainable as long as an economy's wealth
relative to its population is maintained over time. Adjusting for
changes in population size, economic development should be viewed as
growth in wealth, not growth in GNP.
There is a big difference between the two. It is possible to enumerate
many circumstances in which a nation's GNP (per capita) increases over
a period of time even as its wealth (per capita) declines. In broad
terms, those circumstances involve growing markets in certain classes
of goods and services (natural-resource intensive products),
concomitantly with an absence of markets and collective policies for
natural capital (ecosystem services). As global environmental problems
frequently percolate down to create additional stresses on the local
resource bases of the world's poorest people, GNP growth in rich
countries can inflict a downward pressure on the wealth of the poor.
A state of affairs in which GNP increases while wealth declines can't
last for ever. An economy that eats into its productive base in order
to raise current production cannot do so indefinitely. Eventually,
GNP, too, would have to decline, unless policies were to change so
that wealth began to accumulate. That's why it can be hopelessly
misleading to use GNP per head as an index of human well-being.
Recently the World Bank published estimates of the depreciation of a
number of natural resources at the national level. If you were to use
those data (and deploy some low cunning) to estimate changes in wealth
per capita, you would discover that even though GNP per capita has
increased in the Indian subcontinent over the past three decades,
wealth per capita has declined somewhat. The decline has occurred
because, relative to population growth, investment in manufactured
capital, knowledge and skills, and improvements in institutions, have
not compensated for the decline of natural capital. You would find
that in sub-Saharan Africa both GNP per capita and wealth per capita
have declined. You would also confirm that in the world's poorest
regions (Africa and the Indian subcontinent), those that have
experienced higher population growth have also decumulated wealth per
capita at a faster rate. And, finally, you would learn that the
economies of China and the OECD countries, in contrast, have grown
both in terms of GNP per capita and wealth per capita. These regions
have more than substituted for the decline in natural capital by
accumulating other types of capital assets and improving institutions.
It seems that during the past three decades the rich world has enjoyed
sustainable development, while development in the poor world (barring
China) has been unsustainable.
These are early days in the quantitative study of sustainable
development. Even so, one can argue that estimates of wealth movements
in recent history are biased. As regards natural capital, the World
Bank has so far limited itself to taking into account the atmosphere
as a `sink' for carbon dioxide; minerals, oil and natural gas; and
forests as a source of timber. Among the many types of natural capital
whose depreciation has not been included are fresh water; soil;
forests, wetlands, mangroves and coral reefs as providers of ecosystem
services; and the atmosphere as a sink for such forms of pollution as
particulates and nitrogen and sulphur oxides. If these missing items
were to be included, the poor world's economic performance over the
past three decades, including China's, would undoubtedly look a lot
worse. The same would be true for the rich world.
There are further reasons for thinking that the estimates of wealth
changes that I have been referring to are biased. They have to do with
the way prices are estimated for valuing natural capital. Empirical
studies by earth scientists have revealed that the capacity of natural
systems to absorb disturbances is not unlimited. When their absorptive
capacities reach their limit, natural systems are liable to collapse
into unproductive states. Their recovery is costly, both in time and
material resources. If the Gulf Stream were to shift direction or slow
down on account of global warming, the change would to all intents and
purposes be irreversible. We know that up to some unknown set of
limits, knowledge, skills, institutions and manufactured capital can
substitute for nature's resources; meaning that even if an economy
decumulated some of its natural capital, in quantity or quality, its
wealth would increase if it invested sufficiently in other assets. The
remarkable increase in agricultural productivity over the past two
centuries is a case in point. But there are limits to
substitutability: the costs of substitution have been known to
increase in previously unknown ways as key resources are degraded.
Global warming is a case in point. When the downside risks associated
with such limits and thresholds are brought into estimates of
sustainable development, the growth in wealth among the world's
wealthy nations will in all probability turn out to have been less
than present estimates would suggest. It may even have been negative.
What I have sketched here is the correct way to determine whether
contemporary economic development has been sustainable. It is also the
correct way to evaluate public policy, for it tells me that a policy
should be accepted if and only if it is expected to lead to an
increase in wealth per capita. But you won't find any of this in
Diamond's book. There is no evidence that he even realises he doesn't
have the equipment to hand with which to study our interactions with
nature. Nor, as far as I can judge, has he tried to engage with his
economist colleagues to learn whether ecological economists have
anything to say on the matter. The many people who will be reading
Diamond's book will be fascinated by the historical case studies, but
they will also be left with the impression that there is still no
intellectual toolkit with which to deliberate over the most
significant issue facing humanity today. Worse, they may not even
notice they haven't got the tools. So readers will continue as either
environmentalists or environmental sceptics, each locked into their
own perspective. It is a great pity.
[15]Partha Dasgupta's most recent book was Human Well-Being and the
Natural Environment. He is the Frank Ramsey Professor of Economics at
Cambridge and a fellow of St John's College.
References
15. http://www.lrb.co.uk/contribhome.php?get=dasg01
More information about the paleopsych
mailing list